Surviving in a Mediocracy This blog is an
outgrowth of a book on contemporary culture entitled Mediocracy. Some have
assumed the title signifies the standard right-wing complaint that “things ain’t what they used to be”. It’s more complicated than
that. There’s a constellation of
cultural phenomena which are linked, though the nature of the link
isn’t obvious. Dumbing down is part of it, but also
gobbledygook, as well as: obsession with appearance; aggressiveness
as a behavioural norm; the idea that reality is socially constructed; the
dismantling of civil liberties.
Brave
New Academia
Intellectual
taboos
"People shouldn’t think that
the Index is against censorship on principle. It may have been so in its
radical youth, but it is now as concerned with fighting hate speech as
protecting free speech." (Rohan Jayasekera, commenting
about the murder of Theo van Gogh.) Modern collectivised academia (which
ought in theory to act as a forum for free debate) is no different in this
respect. Sacking
academics for “racism”,
because they have dared to consider the possibility that average IQs might differ between
ethnic groups, is the thin end of the wedge. Next on the list is prohibiting
climate change scepticism.
After that may come the protection of other dogmas,
e.g. that inequality is increasing. (I’m not advocating
particular views on these issues; I simply note that some of the possible
answers are becoming impossible to debate.)
Nonsense
on stilts
PROPOSITION 3.2 The model has a
stationary perfect equilibrium. If the game is symmetric, then there exists a
symmetric stationary perfect equilibrium. (i)
cA(z) = cB(z) = zμ for some μ
> 1; (ii)
N ≤ 3 and Assumption C3 holds; (iii) N ≤
5, cA = cB is twice
continuously differentiable, and c″A = c″B is monotonic non-decreasing. (1) An organisation called the Post-Autistic Economics Network (PAECON)
has formed around a group of 'deviants' who don't want to keep quiet about
the fact that economics has become blighted by mathematical gobbledygook.
Unfortunately, PAECON have got this issue mixed up with the claim that modern
economics is biased in a right wing direction. They seem to believe
this because economics tends to focus on markets. I think that's nonsense. It
seems to me that the majority of post-war economists have been pretty desperate to find models which would
justify intervention,
it's just that it hasn't been easy. There's not much that can be proved with
economics beyond the perfect competition model, which — unfortunately, from
many people's point of view — is supportive of free market philosophy. That
is why economists, and other social scientists, got so excited about the Prisoner's Dilemma (which allegedly demonstrates a market
failure) and about game theory generally, and why John Nash is a much more
prominent character in current economics textbooks than Ronald Coase.
Indifference
and hostility Robert Fisk is a man
apparently not much loved by the blogosphere. Yet perhaps there is something
to be said for him. When doing research for the Mediocracy book I
scoured the pages of dozens of publications, looking for criticism of the
prevailing state of academia and its "high on technicality, low on
content" approach. Surely there were some journalists or intellectuals
out there, not academics themselves, prepared to question this ludicrous
state of affairs? In fact, with the exception of a few people like Ophelia Benson pointing out
the absurdities of one specific area (postmodernism), I found not a single
instance. Except this one
allusion to there being a problem — by Mr Fisk. It's
a new and dangerous phenomenon I'm talking about, a language of exclusion
that must have grown up in universities over the past 20 years; after all,
any non-university-educated man or woman can pick up an academic treatise or
PhD thesis written in the 1920s or '30s and — however Hegelian the subject —
fully understand its meaning. No longer. Other mainstream commentators don’t
question this state of affairs, perhaps because they no longer think of
research as something which is capable of being done outside academia, but
simply as whatever happens to be done at universities. The definition of e.g.
philosophy has become, “whatever is done under that name at a recognised
academic institution”. Certification has
become more important than content, and quality is
no longer seen as assessable by an untrained person. The fact that many of
the key innovations in the history of knowledge were made outside
universities is conveniently forgotten. Someone working outside a university
today can be ignored, since by definition they cannot be doing research.
The
few within the academic system who are still prepared to criticise publicly
the changes being forced upon them (e.g. Antony Flew, Anthony O’Hear, Frank Furedi, Kenneth Minogue or Larry Summers) come from the older generation.
When they’ve gone, there may be no one to remind us how things could be
different. The repercussions Why does any of this matter? For two reasons. First, a society
which stifles intellectual innovation is not a healthy society. Second,
certain types of people — e.g. intellectuals not in tune with the dominant
ideology — find it impossible to exist in such a society. They will either
depart for a country which is less stifling, such as the US, or they will
live lives of misery and deprivation. (Here are the real victims of ‘social
exclusion’.) Or, as in my case, they’re forced to try to make significant
amounts of money by investment, in the hope of one day being able to fund an
institutional environment. Some of my fellow academics say, “why whinge about it, just suck
it up. Be grateful you can get paid to have an intellectual career at all”.
They themselves do 'suck it up', and enter into the spirit of New Academe,
helping to perpetuate a system that is basically rotten. It is not that I
haven't tried. For a while I laboured hard to produce the kind of technical economics
which is now de rigueur. But although I learnt well enough how to use the
system of arcane jargon and techniques, it was never quite correct enough in
the required way. I couldn’t quite disabuse myself of the desire to say
something interesting or meaningful. “Don’t try to be original,” I was
advised. “Crank the handle, copy someone else’s work, but with a slight
variation.” “Technique it up” was another frequent suggestion. I.e. wrap up
what you are saying in jargon and presentational gimmicks. Ultimately, my
desire to be clear and consequential proved to be too much of a handicap: I
realised I was never going to be permitted to be anything more than a C-list
academic, and left Oxford. (A severe disappointment, given that my supervisor
at Cambridge had once described me as one of the people most suited to
research he had ever encountered.) Of course, even in the most repressively dogmatic system there
will be the odd lucky exception who somehow slips
through the net. So we get the occasional academic prepared to question the
orthodoxy of their own subject. Usually they do this fairly late in life,
after first having made careers out of supporting the orthodoxy. Recently,
for example, we had a couple of senior academics criticising the economics of
happiness (some months after I had first done
so). Sometimes I wonder whether these 'rebels' are promoted in order
to undermine the claim that there is anything wrong with academia. "See,
it's perfectly possible to be a maverick and still have a respectable
Professorship." Apart from the fact that criticism by such individuals
is generally on the dilute side, the ability to point to a handful of
'dissident' insiders doesn't really bear on the issue of whether it's
possible in general to make a career in academia if you are sceptical of the
orthodoxy to begin with. Especially if you do not have a taste for recycling
what you realise is vacuous, for the sake of climbing the professional ladder
— with the possible compensation of making a secondary career from
criticising what you previously endorsed, thirty years down the line. Pseudo-democratisation Massification of degrees is
said to be inevitable because everyone now aspires to higher education. Fine,
but instead of letting the market provide this extension to the old model, it’s taken to mean turning the university system
into an arm of the welfare
state, rather like the NHS. I.e. run by the state, with everyone having
equal entitlement to a low
grade product, and subsidy based on poverty rather than ability. With the
concept of academic selection increasingly regarded as unacceptable, and
selection in any case becoming impossible as exams are engineered to achieve
egalitarian outcomes, it is not surprising that the idea of university
entrance by lottery is becoming a plausible
option. I have never seen a meaningful case made for a majority needing
to go to college; this is now simply assumed in the most handwaving
way (no substantive argument required) by both Left and Right.
The hidden assumption that ability is not inherited is used to discriminate
against people from social groups considered to be over-represented. The fact
that little of benefit is acquired by most undergraduates is concealed by ensuring
that everyone receives a qualification at the end of the process. The net result is that academics are being forced to become
badly paid handmaidens to a system which will be primarily about promoting equality and inclusion,
like state school teachers already are. They are now also required to comply
with increasing levels of state bureaucracy,
and are monitored and assessed by government auditors — not that this is any
more conducive to quality than its counterpart in the NHS. The modern academic is expected to narrow his or her focus to a
tiny detailed area. Specialisation is usually said to be an inevitable
feature of modern research, but it’s partly a consequence of massification, and the implicit assumption that the whole
academic enterprise should operate as a kind of a hive mind with every cog
playing its small part. Democratisation demands that everyone get 'training' and have a go, and egalitarianism
stipulates that no one is better than anyone else. This creates a system in
which everyone is expected to find a tiny insignificant niche in which to
make themselves comfortable. The level of support is
cut, while the number of 'researchers' is increased. Few people with influence appear to have much incentive to speak
out about this. There are too many vested interests involved. And being
honest for its own sake has become unfashionable. A
small minority of journalists manage to make careers out of criticising the
prevailing cultural ideology, but are apparently unwilling to do the
slightest thing to help exiled academics like me or my colleagues at Oxford
Forum, e.g. by mentioning dissident publications in their newspaper columns.
Though being quite happy, in some cases, to make use of the ideas in their
own writings. It has of course become distinctly unfashionable to criticise
contemporary culture. It’s been done, the story
goes, now get over it. (Though the criticism we’ve had has been principally
about the dumbing down, rather than about the
vacuous technicality.) It doesn’t help that there’s an awful lot of 'academic' activity
out there these days. There are, for example, said to be ten thousand
academic philosophers in the US. This creates the misleading impression that,
whatever requires support at the moment, it is not intellectuals. The web
revolution and its limitations Some think the web will break the stranglehold of the cultural
establishment. Systems like Wikipedia, run largely by intelligent amateurs,
can offer alternative viewpoints, and even criticise some of the more obvious
prejudices of the establishment. (I believe Wikipedia’s success derives
partly from the fact that much of the cultural establishment no longer
generates material that is usable or useful.) The long tail
effect may also help to preserve unfashionable products already in existence
whose influence would otherwise be lost. But technology by itself can only go so far: it can preserve but
it cannot create. Significant cultural innovation requires some individuals
to be free from the usual pressure of earning a living, and that still
depends (as it has always done) on private capital — for which few on the
Left or Right have anything good to say these days. There’s a tendency to
confuse (a) the capacity of the web to criticise nonsense with (b) the
'wisdom of crowds', and to assume that it’s sheer numbers which make the web
valuable. Look for example at the comments section of online Guardian
articles (much heat, little light) and you’ll realise the folly of this. Some people (including some outside the academic establishment)
try to be professional intellectuals on the web, e.g. by having blogs with an
academic flavour. I haven’t bothered myself, because I know the best payoff I
could hope for would be a part-time career on the fringes of journalism. Any
blogger expecting that society will recognise and reward their intellectual
activity on its own merits will certainly be disappointed. The modern world
does not work like that. When my colleague Celia Green tried years
ago to demonstrate her aptitude for research by pioneering several topics of
research in psychology via her own research organisation, all that happened
was that people already in the academic system used her ideas as the basis
for their careers. And that was before the obsession with certification and
institutionalisation had become as pervasive as it is now. Fabian Tassano December
2007 (2) The issue of whether it would do good to marketise the university system is a complex one, not least because any strategy would almost certainly involve partial marketisation. For some background to this, see here. |